Imágenes de páginas
PDF
EPUB

has been only 375 million dollars. And yet, with this comparatively small cash payment, observe what has happened. The mark has declined to less than one-seventieth of the value it had when the obligation to pay was imposed upon Germany, by the Treaty of Versailles. The means of payment has been found by the sale of marks. After this experience it is difficult to believe that Germany has any surplus at the present time from the export of her products.

No Surplus Available from Export of Goods

There is a further consideration in support of this conclusion. It is beyond question that in the last three years Germany has made every effort to develop her external trade. The German workman, whose indus. try and efficiency are generally admitted. has been fully employed and the factories have been actively at work all over the country. The decline in the mark, which at every stage has been much greater in the external than in the internal value, has afforded a very considerable advantage to the German exporter, so much so indeed that there is hardly anywhere a manufacturer, producing goods for export, who does not complain of German competition. Nevertheless. the German trade figures show that the exports, long after the immediate deficiency in essential foreign commodities due to the war was made good, are still barely equal to the imports. The conclusion seems irresistible that Germany has no present capacity to obtain a surplus from the export of goods.

I am not sanguine enough to believe that those who think they can extract from Germany enough money to enable them to meet the internal liabilities, which they themselves have incurred in restoring devastated areas, will be satisfied with the statement I have just made. At the recent Reparation Conference of the Allied Powers held in London proposals were made of punitive meas. ures to be taken with the object of compelling Germany to make immediate cash payments, a policy which could only have been advanced under the conviction that Germany really could pay. For my part I do not be lieve that it is within her power to do so, but let us suppose for a moment that she can. We have then to consider what the effect of this enforced payment would be upon international trade, and whether it would be to the advantage either of Germany's creditors as a whole or of the rest of the world.

If Germany could pay what is demanded of her, the only method of obtaining the money would be by increasing her exports. Now what are these exports to be? She is

essentially a manufacturing nation. Her foreign sale of raw materials is comparatively small. On balance she is obliged to import food, and in consequence of the loss of a large part of her mineral lands she is compelled to import both iron ore and coal for the supply of her factories and furnaces. An increased exportable surplus could only be obtained by extending her sale of manufactured goods. To do this in the teeth of the competition of other manufacturing nations she must work longer hours for less wages, she must cut profits, she must reduce her imports to the indispensable minimum. But her competitors will not consent to stand idle while they lose their trade. They will find themselves faced with growing unemployment and heavy trade losses. So far as German goods seek to invade their own domestic markets they may endeavor to exclude them by tariffs, but in order to retain their hold on neutral markets they too will be compelled to reduce wages and cut profits. And thus Germany's effort to extend her foreign trade must be confronted with the opposition of the whole manufacturing interest of the rest of the world, and could only be successfully countered by a general lowering of the standard of life.

Fall of the German Mark

I know it is frequently alleged that the collapse of the mark with the accompanying disorganization of the world's trade might have been avoided if the German Government had acted with firmness and good faith. It is said that Germany has intentionally depreciated her currency in order to induce her creditors to abandon their claims. We are told that her people are not adequately taxed and that if they were subject to the burdens borne in some other countries, the Government would be able to meet its liabilities. It is certainly true that in my own country far heavier taxation is levied than in Germany, but I am inclined to think we are overtaxed and that overtaxation so far from fostering cannot fail to depress national production. But whether I am right or wrong in that opinion I fail to see how additional taxation can stimulate foreign trade and provide a large exportable surplus. The taxes would be paid in marks, and whether the marks are derived from avowed taxation or from concealed taxation through the use of the printing press, they are in neither case a currency which would be accepted in discharge of foreign liability.

In the actual condition of Germany a foreign sale of marks is an inevitable accom. paniment of the payment of reparations. Except by such sale there does not appear to be any practicable method for the gov

ernment to obtain the necessary foreign currency other than by exacting it from exporters as a condition of their receiving an ex port license. But the exporter, who often has external obligations of his own to meet. does not want marks but dollars or pounds sterling, as the case may be, and forthwith sells the marks paid him by the government for the currency he needs. If we add to this regular sale in the course of business the further sale by Germans who mistrust the stability of their own currency, we have a sufficient explanation of the stupendous drop in the value of German money.

Requisition of Germany's Foreign Assets

Let me come back now to the question of what Germany can pay. Certainly she can pay something, though not in the form or under the conditions it is now sought to impose upon her. Many Germans possess foreign assets, whether investments or balances in foreign banks, and it would be a perfectly practicable proceeding for them to sell these assets to the German Government, who in turn could hand them over to the Reparation Commission. But it is an essential condition of such a transaction that the owners of the foreign assets should be willing to sell them; no government in the present situation of Germany could force a compulsory sale. How then could this consent be obtained? I have no doubt that if these assets could be sold for an assured profit the holders would be willing to dispose of them. It must be remembered that to a considerable extent they are the proceeds of sales of marks which have been flung by Germans on the foreign market under the well-founded apprehension that the pressure of reparation payments would rapidly depreciate their value. lieve this pressure and the mark would immediately improve. It has still a far greater value in Germany than it has outside, and the German holders of foreign assets would have a clear advantage in selling them for marks to their government.

Re.

It is impossible to give any precise estimate of the total value of these assets, but I believe it would be safe to put them at not less than a billion dollars. Whatever the amount may be, however, Germany could pay it, provided the fall in the mark was arrested. More than that I do not think she has the ability to find, at any rate for some years, and it would be a condition of this payment that no more should be demanded of her for a long time to come. I believe that, looking merely at the amount to be received, the creditors would gain by abandoning the attempt to obtain other money pay ments for a period of at least three years,

and I am quite sure the world as a whole would be an immense gainer in the general stabilization of exchanges which would ensue upon an arrest of the fall in the mark. Before I leave this part of my subject there is one observation I should like to make. I have no wish to minimize the just claims of the Allies against Germany, and I recognize the serious political difficulties which stand in the way of their abatement. But no solution of the reparation is possible unless political considerations are subordinated to economic facts. What Germany can pay may not be a simple question, but it is a question capable of being answered. Unfortunately the answer runs counter to popular hopes, popular passions, and, more formidable still, a popular sense of natural jus tice which prescribes that the defeated enemy who planned the war should make good the damage suffered by the victors. And so no authoritative answer is given while Europe slides into ruin.

The Problems of International Debts

I have dealt at length with the reparation problem in an endeavor to show that a nation, except in so far as it has an exportable surplus, can only pay foreign debt out of the wealth it has accumulated outside its own country. If we pass now to the other international debts we have to recognize that the general argument is equally applicable to them all. Have the debtors an exportable surplus and what are their foreign assets? With regard to the latter question the only debtor possessing any large accumulation of such assets is England. Notwithstanding her immense sale of securities to the United States in the second and third years of the war, a sale which largely furnished the means of paying for the goods of all kinds bought by the Allies, England still owns sufficient foreign securities to cover her debt to the United States two or three times over. But neither France nor Italy has similar reserves of wealth, and I doubt whether either of them has sufficient to meet more than a trifling part of their foreign debt.

There remains to be considered their exportable surplus in the ordinary way of trade.. I shall speak later of the circumstances in which an exportable surplus from production usually arises, and I shall give my reasons for thinking that nothing more than comparatively small annual payments can ever be made in this way. But it will be more convenient now to deal with an individual debt and I will ask you to consider the particular case of the debt from France to England, which I ean speak about with more freedom as it is a debt in regard to

which my own country is the creditor. We shall get a clearer view of it if we examine the circumstances in which it was incurred.

During the war France developed an immense demand for goods of foreign production. As an increasing proportion of her man power became engaged in her army, her capacity to supply herself was progressively reduced. She had no abundance of foreign securities with which to pay for her require ments and she could obtain the war materials indispensable for the maintenance of the fight in no other way than by borrowing the money to pay for them. Before the United States came into the war France had borrowed 1 billion dollars from the British Government, and this amount was subsequently increased to over 22 billion dollars The price of the goods bought by Francc was naturally high. Commodities produced to meet an urgent war need can never be cheap. But France was obliged to have the goods, whatever the price, and a great stimulus was given to American and British trade.

Situation as to French Debt

Let us now reverse the process and imagine France paying off this debt. She could only do so by producing goods and exporting them in very large quantities, far in excess of normal trade demands. If the general trade organization of the world permitted of the absorption of this additional French out. put, I have no doubt that her industry would be capable of the effort necessary to enable her to pay interest and sinking fund on her debt. But would there be any willingness to receive the goods? Neither England nor any other country is prepared today to pay for and consume goods on an exceptional scale. The immense demand created by the war has no parallel in peace. And yet how is France to pay unless an exceptional demand exists. The truth is that her debt is far too great in relation to ordinary international trade possibilities. It was incurred by the purchase of goods required in war and bought at war prices. It could only be discharged by the transmission of goods, not wanted in peace and sold at no less high prices. We became accustomed in war to talk in billions. Our language was suited to the circumstances of the time, but, if we carry our minds back to 1914 and return to the ideas appropriate to peace conditions, we shall recognize at once that France has no trade surplus or reserves of accumulated and exportable wealth to enable her to meet her present external liabilities.

There are of course conceivable, though I trust improbable, conditions in which the French debt to us might be repaid. If we

were at war and the call upon our men to line the trenches was such that many of our mines and factories had to close down; and if France were at peace and at liberty to increase her output to the utmost of her capacity she might pour upon our shores war material and stores equal to the whole amount of her debt to us. But in what part of the globe is there a demand for this addi tional output in time of peace? The mere endeavor to extend her foreign sales to the necessary degree would disorganize the trade of the world. We have seen the painful effect of an enforced competition by Germany; we should experience precisely the same results from a similar effort by France

The inevitable conclusion is that these international debts are far too great for the 'capacity of any of the debtor countries except England. She alone in her accumulated foreign investments has adequate resources with which to discharge her liability to the United States. Of the others, France has the greatest resources, but they are, I be lieve, quite insufficient to meet her obligations. The whole subject requires a rational reconsideration by the creditors, who must keep steadily in view the immediate effect of the payment of these debts on the general trade of the world. The creditor countries will obtain greater advantage from trade prosperity, which will ensure full employ ment in their factories and workshops, than they can ever receive from the precarious payment of these debts. In the last two years we have had experience of the effect upon foreign trade of tumbling exchanges and broken-down credit, apd though the consequences may be more us in England than in the United States, where foreign trade is comparatively only a small part of. the total trade, they are still grave enough in the latter country also to warrant the fullest and most careful consideration.

It may be objected that my argument appears to lead to the unpalatable conclusion that no nation, unless it has accumulated resources in the form of foreign investments, can discharge external obligations to anything more than a comparatively small amount. This is an objection which goes to the very root of the question of international loans and forces us to a consideration of the real meaning of an exportable surplus. I cannot do more than touch upon it briefly now without stretching your patience beyond the limit of extreme good nature.

British Experience as Creditor Nation

It seems to me that the most compact form in which I can present the case is by calling your attention to the experience of England

as a creditor country. For over two centuries British capital has been lent to other countries. Year by year England produced more than she either consumed herself or could exchange for the products of other nations, and she could not obtain a market for the surplus unless she gave the purchaser a long credit. Foreign loans and foreign issues of all kinds were taken up in England and the proceeds were spent in paying for the surplus production. British factories and workshops were kept in good employment, but it was a condition of their prosperity that a part of their output should be disposed of in this way. Taking the aggregate of the transactions British creditors have received a good return on their investment, but the ability of the debtors to pay has been dependent, speaking generally, on the development of their country being fostered by the receipt of further loans. If we take the whole field of British foreign investment we shall find that every year England has returned in loan more than she received in interest, and the balance of the world's indebtedness to her has been steadily grow. ing.

From this view of loans made to foreign countries they might seem at first sight to be somewhat unremunerative. If the creditor has to go on lending in order to be paid the interest on previous loans, a bad debt would appear to be the only possible end to the business. But this is by no means the case. While this continuous lending has been true in the past in the aggregate of foreign loans, it is not necessarily true in any individual instance, nor does it follow that it will always be true of the loans as a whole. our experience as bankers it is not uncommon to see loans to corporations and firms justifiably increasing in amount. The borrower may show by the growth of his busi ness and expanding turnover that such advances are thoroughly warranted, and in spite of his greater total of indebtedness his credit may be improving and his balancesheet may disclose an increasing surplus.

In

What is true of an individual or corporation may be true of a country, but on a larger scale and viewed over a much more extended period of time. The life of an individual or even of the most successful company is as nothing compared with the life of a nation. Take the case of your own country; the United States has been the greatest external borrower.in history. You required foreign capital for your internal development and you took from England alone not less than 3 billion dollars. It is estimated that at the time of the outbreak of the war your external debt had become

stationary in amount, and that your exportable surplus of commodities sufficed to pay the whole of the interest. Repayment of the capital, however, would have been beyond even your capacity for a very long period had it not been for the opportunity afforded by the war. As you know there arose then an inexhaustible demand in Europe for American goods which led to an immense increase in your exports. Payment for these exports was largely made out of the proceeds of the sale of the stocks and bonds held in England, and thus a capital liability which had been growing for over two centuries was almost entirely discharged in a few years.

Misunderstanding as to International Payment

We see then that a debtor nation may in certain circumstances pay off its foreign debt with remarkable ease and rapidity. The indispensable condition for such rapid repayment is that there should be an extraordinary demand for its goods, a demand which is a natural accompaniment of war but does not exist in peace. I cannot help thinking that there has been a general, though very natural, misunderstanding of the conditions under which international payments are made. In its present magnitude the subject is new. In the past we have been accustomed only to the discharge of comparatively small liabilities between nations which has been effected partly by the remittance of gold, and partly by an extension of export trade facilitated by a fall in the exchange of the debtor country, and it is not easy for us now to free ourselves from the ideals we have formed in the course of our past experience.

Mistaken opinions on these economic questions are not surprising, but they are causing grave disasters throughout the world. It is not many years ago-it is well within my own recollection-that a want of understanding of sound principles of banking led to repeated financial crises which were then believed to be inevitable. As they usually happened at intervals of ten or eleven years many serious persons attributed them to the variations which occur in the spots on the sun. These spots may affect the weather, and, through the weather, the harvest, but a wider knowledge of banking and of currency requirements has taught us how to escape their malign influence on credit. A better understanding of international trade and of the possible limits of international payments will quickly enable us to find a remedy for the evils which now distract us. The public on both sides of the Atlantic are beginning to take a more rational view than

was possible three years ago, and if the leaders of opinion direct our footsteps along the right path I believe the world is now prepared to follow it.

To sum up: the conclusion to which I am driven is that Germany can only pay now whatever she may have in foreign balances together with such amount as she can reailze by the sale of her remaining foreign securities; that this payment is only possible if all other demands are postponed for a defi nite period long enough to ensure the stabili zation of the mark; and that future demands at the expiration of this period must be limited to the annual amount of Germany's exportable surplus at that time. Further, that England has the capacity to pay to the United States interest and sinking fund on her debt; but that the other debtors are none of them in a position to meet more than a small part of their external liabilities, and in the existing condition of Europe a definite postponement of any payment by them is desirable in the interests of all the parties. The actual amount which the other debtors could ultimately pay should, as in the case of Germany, be ascertained by enquiry into their exportable surplus at a full and frank conference between creditors and debtors. I have strictly confined myself to

a

consideration of the economic aspect of reparations and international debts, how they are payable, the general capacity of a debtor country to pay, and the effect of payment. If I have become convinced that an attempt to enforce payment beyond the debtor's ability is injurious to the international trade of the whole world, lowers wages, reduces profits and is a direct cause of unemployment, the conclusion is founded solely on economic grounds and is uninfluenced by any political considerations or any regard 1 to the moral obligations of the debtors. know very well that there. are other considerations affecting these debts, but these are matters of statecraft to be determined by the rulers of the creditor countries ac. cording to their view of wise policy, which covers many interests besides those of trade and finance. The fact that a debtor cannot pay does not of itself discharge the obligation. The debt may become the subject of negotiation and bargain by which if the debtor obtains relief, the creditor may still recover some advantage to which he may be justly entitled. But I conceive it to be. the duty of bankers to help so far as they can in forming a sound public opinion upon the financial and commercial aspects of these international debts.

[graphic][merged small]
« AnteriorContinuar »